Introduction
Fisheries in the open ocean are just one example of a common pool resource
that can be exploited by anyone and is sensitive to over exploitation.
Common pool resources are resources that have high subtractability (any
use subtracts the resource from any other use) and where exclusion from
the resource is difficult (anyone can gain entry). There are other classifications
of resources that would have different problems and appropriate solutions.
Table 1: Resource classification by subtractability and exclusion.
Subtractability means that a use of one unit of the resource removes
that unit from anyone else's use. Exclusion is whether it is easy to
limit access or impossible.
|
low
subtractability |
high
subtractability |
difficult
exclusion |
public
goods |
common pool
resources |
easy
exclusion |
toll
goods |
private
goods |
Maximum sustainable yield and over harvest. The amount
of fish that is taken in any season is the "yield". Ecosystem
managers calculate the maximum sustainable yield as the maximum value
of the population times the growth rate. At low population size the yield
is limited by the number of reproducing fish. At high populations the
yield is limited by the decrease in the growth rate from inter- and intra-specific
competition for resources. The maximum sustainable yield is the theoretical
maximum point that is half of the carrying capacity. Over harvest can
happen in two ways, either the maximum yield is an overestimate or a correct
MSY could be taken too early when the population is still too small. Over
harvest decreases that population such that the growth for the next season
will be decreased. Thus Over harvest and early-harvest are related processes.
Figure 1. a- Theoretical optimal sustainable yield for a population
going through a logistic growth transition. Early in the growth phase,
the population growth is controlled by rapid growth rate and the number
of fish. Later, the population growth (yield) is dominated the decrease
in the intrinsic growth rate as the population reaches the carrying
capacity. In the middle of the curve, the highest slope, is the population
value that will give the highest yield. b - when the maximum sustainable
yield is initiated just as the population gets to the midpoint, the
population will stay constant. c- If the harvest is higher than the
maximum sustainable yield, the population will decrease. d- Applying
the maximum harvesting rate before the population has reached the mid-point
will also result in a decrease in the population.
Logistic growth curve
|
Maximum harvest at the midpoint is sustainable
|
Over harvest at the midpoint leads to decline |
Maximum harvest, but early, leads to decline |
This theoretical maximum yield should be reduced for several reasons.
The process of harvesting can degrade the conditions necessary for optimal
growth. Too many roads in the forest, catching too many non-target fish
or trampling of a pasture are examples of this type of damage. It reduces
the ability of the environment to grow the resource without directly showing
up in the harvest. Natural variability in the conditions should also be
accounted for in calculating the actually yield that can be tolerated.
Variations in weather or other populations in the ecosystem can result
in good and bad seasons for growth. Maximal harvesting during a bad year
can decrease the population below the sustainable level. Often the variability
is a source of uncertainty for ecosystem managers. Still, they need to
be able to make decisions to set a harvest rate and to be take precautions
against the collapse of the fishery.
Variability in fishery production. Even healthy natural
environments undergo swings in the overall productivity and especially
the growth of one species in the food web. Understanding that this variability
was a key component of our attempt to understand food webs using a network
view.The degree of variability can be quite large and the system can stay
healthy. However, with artificially harvest superimposed on top of natural
variability, the results can be disastrous. The following simulations
(Figure 2) demonstrate the effects of a population that is either fished,
or perturbed by a density dependent loss, or both. Each simulation run
represents one possible trajectory through time, with random events. There
is a range of outcomes, and each can be predicted roughly from the probability
of the loss (Figure 3). Given the dynamic nature of natural ecosystems,
it may not be possible to determine the probability of loss to any degree
of certainty, i.e. the loss may be uncertain no matter how much this population
were studied.
Figure 2. Simulation results for a fish stock that is growing with
and with harvest and stochastic loss terms. The parameters for all models
are r=.3, K=2400, initial population =800. The population is controlled
by the logistic equation. The stochastic loss is a random percent loss
(up to the maximum of a 10% loss) times the population. a- growth with
no fishing. b - growth with a harvest of 100. c. stochastic loss only.
d- harvest and up to a 10% stochastic loss combined.
fig2a - no harvest
fig2b - harvest rate of 100
fig2c - on example run with a stochastic loss of up to 10% of the population
per time
fig2d - one example run with both a constant harvest of 100 and a stochastic
loss of up to 10% of the population per time.
Figure 3. With any stochastic loss there are multiple trajectories
for the population. a - one selected output that shows a collapse of
the population. b - another selected output that shows increase in the
population over the period shown
There are many ways to cause extinction. Just as it
was claimed that "all roads lead to Rome", it seems that for
our current civilization, all roads lie perilously close to causing extinction
and collapse of our natural resources. Our choice to exploit natural resources
must be accompanied with taking responsibility for our actions and the
consequences for the environment.
We face two fundamental decisions when we use of natural resources. If
the resource is a "common pool resource", we have to decide
how we will adjust our use to that of other users. How will we know if
we are overexploiting the resource? The second question we face is how
to deal with the uncertainty in the system and to abide by the "precautionary
principle" which states that in the face of uncertainty, choose the
path that will do the least damage
In this case study and accompanying framework discussion, we will explore
how to structure these decisions as game, either a game against other
possible users of the resource or as a game against nature to deal with
uncertainty.
|